Winning bid: how auction theory took the Nobel memorial prize in economics | 拍賣理論爲什麼能得諾貝爾獎? - FT中文網
登錄×
電子郵件/用戶名
密碼
記住我
請輸入郵箱和密碼進行綁定操作:
請輸入手機號碼,透過簡訊驗證(目前僅支援中國大陸地區的手機號):
請您閱讀我們的用戶註冊協議私隱權保護政策,點擊下方按鈕即視爲您接受。
FT英語電臺

Winning bid: how auction theory took the Nobel memorial prize in economics
拍賣理論爲什麼能得諾貝爾獎?

Paul Milgrom and Robert Wilson』s work transformed how countries allocate resources in the public interest
保羅·米爾格羅姆和羅伯特·威爾遜的工作改變了國家爲公共利益分配資源的方式。
00:00

If you and I were to bid against each other in a charity auction for, say, dinner with Princess Marie of Denmark, little would have to be explained about how the details of the auction work. One of us values the prospect more, would pay more, and would win.

But if you and I were bidding against each other for the joint value of the cash in our wallets, the auction becomes far more intriguing. I know only what is in my wallet and you know only what is in yours. Each of us should take a keen interest in what the other is willing to pay, since it is a clear signal of the value of the prize.

The charity auction for an evening with Princess Marie would be described by an economist as a private value auction. I have my own idea of its value, you have yours and the only question is whose value — and thus whose bid — is higher.

The wallet auction is known as a common value auction. The cash in the wallets is worth the same to each of us. To add to the intrigue, each of us has a piece of the puzzle but neither of us know everything about the true value.

This is a hint of the complexities involved in the ostensibly simple process of running an auction, or bidding in one. Auctions date back a long time. Almost 2,500 years ago, the historian Herodotus described men bidding for the most attractive wives in Babylon. Auctions also appear in Edward Gibbon』s The History of the Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire, as well as in Samuel Pepys』s diaries.

Presumably, the auction is almost as old as the marketplace itself. It was no doubt invented many times over in markets when some buyer offered to pay four denarii per jar for fresh honey, and the man next to him said, 「don』t settle for that price — I』ll give you five」.

The economist William Vickrey shared a Nobel memorial prize in 1996 in part for his foundational work on the theory of auctions. But Vickrey』s work, while elegant to the point of beauty, does not give economists the tools to analyse the complex, practical auction design problems that real world settings require.

Into the breach stepped Robert Wilson and his former student Paul Milgrom, the Stanford professors who today have shared the 2020 Nobel memorial prize in economic sciences 「for improvements to auction theory and inventions of new auction formats」.

Paul Klemperer, a leading auction theorist at Oxford university, says that even the Nobel citation is hardly praise enough. These were not just 『improvements』. 「Robert Wilson is the father of practical auction design,」 he said, 「and Paul Milgrom could easily have won a second Nobel Prize for his work on the economics of information」.

The peak of the excitement around spectrum auctions came at the turn of the century, when European countries auctioned spectrum rights at the height of dotcom mania

Beyond the beauty of auction theory, the reason this matters is that governments have turned to auctions over the past few decades to allocate resources including logging rights, mineral exploration rights and the rights to use particular frequencies of radio spectrum for television or mobile phones. The alternative — handing out the resources cheaply to whoever spins the most plausible story — offers some conveniences to both buyers and politicians but is hardly in the public interest.

A well-designed auction forces bidders to reveal the truth about their own estimate of the prize』s value. At the same time, the auction shares that information with the other bidders. And it sets the price accordingly. It is quite a trick.

But, in practice, it is a difficult trick to get right. In the 1990s, the US Federal government turned to auction theorists — Milgrom and Wilson prominent among them — for advice on auctioning radio-spectrum rights. 「The theory that we had in place had only a little bit to do with the problems that they actually faced,」 Milgrom recalled in an interview in 2007. But the proposals that were being made by the government were proposals that we were perfectly capable of analysing the flaws in and improving.

The basic challenge with radio-spectrum auctions is that many prizes are on offer, and bidders desire only certain combinations. A TV company might want the right to use Band A, or Band B, but not both. Or the right to broadcast in the east of England, but only if they also had the right to broadcast in the west. Such combinatorial auctions are formidably challenging to design, but Milgrom and Wilson got to work.

Joshua Gans, a former student of Milgrom』s who is now a professor at the University of Toronto, praises both men for their practicality. Their theoretical work is impressive, he said, 「but they realised that when the world got too complex, they shouldn』t adhere to proving strict theorems」.

The peak of the excitement around spectrum auctions came at the turn of the century, when European countries auctioned spectrum rights at the height of dotcom mania. But auctions continue to be used to allocate scarce resources, and there is ample room to use them in future — for example, allocating the rights to fly to hub airports or the right to emit carbon dioxide, deciding which environmental projects should receive subsidies, or providing central bank loans to the banking system in times of stress.

Spectrum auctions have already raised many billions of dollars across the world; Milgrom, Wilson and another auction designer, Preston McAfee, were awarded a Golden Goose Award in 2014 — the award celebrates apparently obscure research that yields large social benefits.

And it is not just governments who use auctions. Every time you type a search term into Google, the advertisements you see alongside the results are there because they won a complex auction. Auctions helped to allocate the infrastructure on which the internet runs. Now they help to allocate our attention.

Tim Harford』s new book is 「How to Make the World Add Up

版權聲明:本文版權歸FT中文網所有,未經允許任何單位或個人不得轉載,複製或以任何其他方式使用本文全部或部分,侵權必究。

油價疲軟加劇沙烏地大型項目建設壓力

沙烏地阿拉伯準備解除減產措施,但這可能會危及其雄心勃勃的支出計劃。

國防開支激增,利基礦物價格飆升

從子彈到先進戰鬥機所需的材料都面臨著嚴重的供應短缺問題 。

英國車企支援首相不報復川普的汽車關稅

汽車製造商要求大臣們制定一個「整體方法」來支援英國汽車工業。

歐盟多國推動縮減對川普關稅的報復措施

法國、愛爾蘭和義大利等國反對歐盟提議的反擊美國關稅的措施。

美國在石油制裁問題上給予塞爾維亞更多寬限

美國的延期讓這個巴爾幹國家有30天的時間爲俄羅斯在塞爾維亞唯一煉油廠的多數股權尋找買家,從而避免了該國的能源危機。

川普吊銷石油公司在委內瑞拉的運營許可證

繼雪佛龍公司之後,埃尼公司和全球油碼頭公司也被撤銷許可證。美國此舉是爲了向馬杜洛政府加大施壓力度。
11小時前
設置字型大小×
最小
較小
默認
較大
最大
分享×